Tag Archives: Friedrich August von Hayek

Chicago Economics

Chicagonomics, a new book by Lanny Ebenstein, describes the evolution of the Chicago school. The book is reviewed by Tyler Cowen in a blog post and by the Economist. From the latter review:

Before the 1940s, Chicago’s professors were much closer to the liberalism of British political economists such as Adam Smith, Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill than the libertarianism of Hayek and Friedman in the 1980s and early 1990s. Mr Ebenstein looks at the ideas of scholars such as Jacob Viner and Frank Knight, and concludes that while they favoured individual freedom, their policy prescriptions did not exclude government action. Both perceived Smith as justifying the state intervening in the economy at times, such as with the provision of infrastructure, education for the young and the funding of arts, culture and science.

By the 1940s, the use of redistribution to ensure that everyone had a basic standard of living was accepted by most Chicago economists. For instance, Henry Simons, when he worked at Chicago between 1939 and 1946, set out how redistribution, by diffusing economic power in a society, was necessary in a free society. Even Hayek, in his libertarian polemic of 1944, “The Road to Serfdom”, supported the use of environmental regulation and state-run social-insurance systems.

After they retired Hayek and Friedman became deeply libertarian. Mr Ebenstein says “the virtual neoanarchism that both preached” later on placed them “outside the classical liberal tradition”. Hayek argued that citizens should have the right to have their taxes refunded if they did not consume government services and Friedman railed “against government at almost any time”. Both enjoyed being in the limelight, even though their views did not fit with their earlier scholarly work. Mr Ebenstein bemoans the current popular perception of the Chicago school, as well as conservatives’ embrace of it, as based on these more extreme later utterances.

 

Hayek’s “Why I am not a Conservative”

Cass Sunstein interprets Friedrich von Hayek’s “Why I am not a Conservative” in BloombergView.

According to Sunstein, Hayek endorsed Conservatives’ skepticism about rapid change and social engineering and appreciated their understanding of the value of institutions that grow out of decentralised interaction rather than centralised social design. At the same time, Hayek saw Conservatives as objecting to novelty as such and complained that they did not “welcome the same undesigned change from which new tools of human endeavor will emerge.” And he complained that they are far too fond of established authority (“The conservative does not object to coercion or arbitrary power so long as it is used for what he regards as the right purposes.”) and have difficulty cooperating with people who don’t share their moral values. Sunstein: Instead of conservatism, Hayek argued for a principled commitment to liberty, “directed against popular prejudices, entrenched positions and firmly established privileges.”